Global Central Bank Focus

The Global Factor in Neutral Policy Rates

A global factor helps explain why central bank policies often tend to be correlated across countries.

The concept of the neutral fed funds rate – often referred to as r* by Federal Reserve researchers and others – has become central to understanding how the Fed thinks about and communicates its plans for policy normalization at the same time that it begins the process of shrinking its balance sheet.

We’ve been writing about this New Neutral for monetary policy in a global context since 2014, and over the intervening years, both Fed thinking and market pricing have converged to the view that r* – the Fed policy rate consistent with 2% inflation and full employment in the U.S. economy – is much closer to 2% than to the pre-crisis estimates of 4% or greater.

What is perhaps less appreciated is the global component that drives neutral policy rates in different countries. Understanding that there is a significant global factor in neutral policy rates is crucial to understanding why central bank policies tend to be correlated across countries and how exchange rates and markets are likely to react to changes in policy.

Each country’s neutral rate may reflect the state of the global business cycle

At the annual Bank for International Settlements (BIS) research conference in June, I presented a paper on “The Global Factor in Neutral Policy Rates.”1 The focus, summarized here, is the practical implications for monetary policy and foreign exchange rates in a world of correlated r* shocks.

How does this model work?

In the original Taylor Rule, r* is assumed to be constant so that only a country’s inflation rate and output gap influence changes in the policy rate. However, the original Taylor rule can be easily modified to allow for a time-varying r*and for this time-varying r* to depend in part on the state of the global economy.

For example, Holston, Laubach and Williams (see Figure 1) show empirically that the neutral real policy rate in the U.S., UK, eurozone and Canada is a function of expected trend growth in each country. So if there is a common factor across countries in productivity growth, there will be a common factor in neutral policy rates. In the BIS paper, I show that in the sort of macro models that many central banks use to conduct policy simulations, r* in each country will also be a function of the state of the global business cycle. As a result, even when home and foreign fundamentals are statistically independent, if countries are adjusting policy in response to common, global neutral real rate shocks, there may well be a positive correlation in policy – even in the absence of policy cooperation or coordination. (I discuss central bank correlation, coordination and cooperation below and also in a prior edition of Global Central Bank Focus.)

autumn Fed building

Currency effects

In a world of r* shocks, exchange rates will tend to respond not to the global factor in r* but instead to a country’s deviations in its r* from the global average (see Figure 2, in which the movement in the trade-weighted value of the U.S. dollar responds to the U.S. neutral policy rate’s variation relative to that of the eurozone, UK and Canada, following a lag). In that case, exchange rate depreciation in the face of a country-specific decline in r* shocks may not in and of itself signal a “beggar-thy-neighbor” policy. By contrast, no exchange rate adjustment may be required for global (rather than country-specific) r* shocks. In response to a global shock, a common global decline in real policy rates can do all the work to attain macroeconomic adjustment. This may look like, but is not necessarily evidence of a global “currency war” with a “race to the bottom” in policy rates as countries seek to avoid rate differentials and home currency appreciation as other countries cut interest rates.

U.S. dollar movements in response to U.S. r* variation from r* across major economies

Coordinated efforts

What about the potential gains from monetary policy coordination among different countries? To the extent a foreign central bank has some comparative advantage in “nowcasting” or forecasting productivity growth, its business cycle or its policy reaction function and r*, sharing this information with other central banks could improve the effectiveness of each bank’s policy in meeting its domestic objectives. In practice, since r* is not observable, coordination in such efforts could be very valuable at creating better estimates.

The ties that bind

While this model works in theory, what are the practical problems with taking global monetary policy one step further by engaging in cooperation? In practice, the cost to a regime of policy cooperation – in the sense of cooperative game theory – could be larger than the theoretical benefits. The problems include the threat to the credibility of the central bank, the challenges to central bank communication, and the resulting potential loss of public support for policymakers’ sound, rules-based decisions when the policy choices required by binding cooperation react not only to home inflation but also to deviations of foreign inflation from target. For example, if home inflation is above target but foreign inflation is below target, the optimal policy rule under cooperation calls for the home (real) policy rate to be lower – more accommodative – than it would be in the absence of cooperation. The divergence between economic conditions in the home country and the policy rate set under a cooperative policy would be politically untenable. In light of these inherent challenges to formal global monetary policy cooperation, its absence from the world stage is not a surprise, and very likely a good thing.

The global factor present in r* policy rates around the world may inform and influence policy decisions and prompt useful coordination – but likely not binding cooperation – that ultimately could benefit the global economy.

For PIMCO’s insights into central bank decisions and other macro factors influencing the near-term economic forecast, please read our latest Cyclical Outlook, “As Good as It Gets.”

Read Here

1 Clarida, Richard H. “The Global Factor in Neutral Policy Rates: Some Implications for Exchange Rates, Monetary Policy, and Policy Coordination,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 23562 (June 2017), http://www.nber.org/papers/w23562. Presented at BIS Annual Conference on 23 June 2017: http://www.bis.org/events/conf170623/clarida.pdf
The Author

Richard Clarida

Global Strategic Advisor

View Profile

Latest Insights

Disclosures

Pacific Investment Management Company LLC, 650 Newport Center Drive, Newport Beach, CA 92660 is regulated by the United States Securities and Exchange Commission. | PIMCO Europe Ltd (Company No. 2604517), PIMCO Europe, Ltd Amsterdam Branch (Company No. 24319743), and PIMCO Europe Ltd- Italy (Company No. 07533910969) are authorised and regulated by the Financial Conduct Authority (25 The North Colonnade, Canary Wharf, London E14 5HS) in the UK. The Amsterdam and Italy Branches are additionally regulated by the AFM and CONSOB in accordance with Article 27 of the Italian Consolidated Financial Act, respectively. PIMCO Europe Ltd services and products are available only to professional clients as defined in the Financial Conduct Authority’s Handbook and are not available to individual investors, who should not rely on this communication. | PIMCO Deutschland GmbH(Company No. 192083, Seidlstr. 24-24a, 80335 Munich, Germany) is authorised and regulated by the German Federal Financial Supervisory Authority (BaFin) (Marie- Curie-Str. 24-28, 60439 Frankfurt am Main) in Germany in accordance with Section 32 of the German Banking Act (KWG). The services and products provided by PIMCO Deutschland GmbH are available only to professional clients as defined in Section 31a para. 2 German Securities Trading Act (WpHG). They are not available to individual investors, who should not rely on this communication. | PIMCO (Schweiz) GmbH (registered in Switzerland, Company No. CH-020.4.038.582-2), Brandschenkestrasse 41, 8002 Zurich, Switzerland, Tel: + 41 44 512 49 10. The services and products provided by PIMCO Switzerland GmbH are not available to individual investors, who should not rely on this communication but contact their financial adviser. | PIMCO Asia Pte Ltd (8 Marina View, #30-01, Asia Square Tower 1, Singapore 018960, Registration No. 199804652K) is regulated by the Monetary Authority of Singapore as a holder of a capital markets services licence and an exempt financial adviser. The asset management services and investment products are not available to persons where provision of such services and products is unauthorised. | PIMCO Asia Limited (Suite 2201, 22nd Floor, Two International Finance Centre, No. 8 Finance Street, Central, Hong Kong) is licensed by the Securities and Futures Commission for Types 1, 4 and 9 regulated activities under the Securities and Futures Ordinance. The asset management services and investment products are not available to persons where provision of such services and products is unauthorised. | PIMCO Australia Pty Ltd ABN 54 084 280 508, AFSL 246862 (PIMCO Australia) offers products and services to both wholesale and retail clients as defined in the Corporations Act 2001 (limited to general financial product advice in the case of retail clients). This communication is provided for general information only without taking into account the objectives, financial situation or needs of any particular investors. | PIMCO Japan Ltd (Toranomon Towers Office 18F, 4-1-28, Toranomon, Minato-ku, Tokyo, Japan 105-0001) Financial Instruments Business Registration Number is Director of Kanto Local Finance Bureau (Financial Instruments Firm) No.382. PIMCO Japan Ltd is a member of Japan Investment Advisers Association and The Investment Trusts Association, Japan. Investment management products and services offered by PIMCO Japan Ltd are offered only to persons within its respective jurisdiction, and are not available to persons where provision of such products or services is unauthorized. Valuations of assets will fluctuate based upon prices of securities and values of derivative transactions in the portfolio, market conditions, interest rates, and credit risk, among others. Investments in foreign currency denominated assets will be affected by foreign exchange rates. There is no guarantee that the principal amount of the investment will be preserved, or that a certain return will be realized; the investment could suffer a loss. All profits and losses incur to the investor. The amounts, maximum amounts and calculation methodologies of each type of fee and expense and their total amounts will vary depending on the investment strategy, the status of investment performance, period of management and outstanding balance of assets and thus such fees and expenses cannot be set forth herein. | PIMCO Canada Corp. (199 Bay Street, Suite 2050, Commerce Court Station, P.O. Box 363, Toronto, ON, M5L 1G2) services and products may only be available in certain provinces or territories of Canada and only through dealers authorized for that purpose. | PIMCO Latin America Edifício Internacional Rio Praia do Flamengo, 154 1° andar, Rio de Janeiro – RJ Brasil 22210-906.

This material contains the opinions of the manager and such opinions are subject to change without notice. This material has been distributed for informational purposes only and should not be considered as investment advice or a recommendation of any particular security, strategy or investment product. Information contained herein has been obtained from sources believed to be reliable, but not guaranteed. No part of this material may be reproduced in any form, or referred to in any other publication, without express written permission. PIMCO is a trademark of Allianz Asset Management of America L.P. in the United States and throughout the world. THE NEW NEUTRAL is a trademark of Pacific Investment Management Company LLC in the United States and throughout the world. ©2017, PIMCO.